Cannabis News Stop the Drug War!
  This is a Bust: The Futility of Drug Interdiction
Posted by FoM on June 21, 2001 at 14:24:03 PT
Editorial 
Source: National Review 

justice The drug war works, at least in Bolivia. Between 1995 and 2000, the amount of land in Bolivia with coca cultivated on it declined from almost 50,000 hectares to fewer than 20,000. In Peru, during the same period, land under cultivation for coca declined from 115,000 hectares to roughly 30,000. It was a nice winning streak for the American policy of coca eradication in the Andes, except for the minor matter of Colombia, where the coca crop doubled-keeping the level of production in the Andes approximately the same as it had been before those victories in Bolivia and Peru.

In the drug war, the victories never end, because they never last. Last year's annual report from the Office of National Drug Control Policy noted progress in the Caribbean: A "decline in the cocaine trafficking in Jamaica, the Bahamas, and Cuba followed the execution of several joint interdiction operations in the area." But wait: "There were . . . increases in overall drug trafficking in Haiti, the Dominican Republic, and Puerto Rico as well as smuggling through fishing vessels in the Eastern Pacific." It's a wonder that drug warriors make even this "one-step forward, one-step back" progress.

The report notes, matter-of-factly: "Drugs coming to the United States from South America pass through a six million square-mile transit zone roughly the size of the continental United States." Oh, is that all?

As a Council on Foreign Relations report on drug-eradication and - -interdiction policies puts it, "For twenty years, these programs have done little more than rearrange the map of drug production and trafficking." There is more rearranging yet to come. Bush drug-czar nominee John Walters is, in drug-war terms, a die-hard supply-sider, convinced that more aerial spraying and harsher measures against traffickers will squeeze the drug supply in America, force up prices, and prompt addicts to drop their habit.

Together with his mentor and czarist predecessor Bill Bennett, Walters champions a kind of drug-war Brezhnev doctrine in which no drug-policy excess-the tougher penalty for crack compared with powder cocaine, mandatory-minimum sentencing laws, the ban on the medicinal use of marijuana-is ever to be rolled back. The current American escalation in the Andes, pushing the drug war further toward a real shooting proposition, is just another step in this hard-line logic.

The $1.3 billion Plan Colombia, originally funded by the Clinton administration and now being refashioned into a broader, even more expensive Andes-wide initiative by the Bush administration, will throw a massive amount of military aid, including Black Hawk helicopters, into the breach in Colombia. It will likely succeed the way so many other drug-war initiatives do-fitfully and temporarily, if it all. To examine the supply-side drug policies in behalf of which American money, materiel, and prestige will be expended in Colombia is to see the free (in this case, black) market working in all its marvelous and appalling ingenuity, frustrating the drug warriors, whose efforts constantly double back on themselves like a cat chasing its tail. In its dishonesty and strategic confusion, Plan Colombia is-to paraphrase Omar Bradley-the wrong war, at the wrong place, at the wrong time, and with the wrong enemy.

The economics of drug production will always bedevil drug warriors.

Take efforts to destroy coca leaf through eradication. Such efforts will have little effect on consumption in the U.S., since the price of coca leaf is such a tiny fraction of the street price of cocaine.

Expecting eradication to drive up retail drug prices is like increasing the cost of dashboard cupholders in hopes of raising the showroom price of automobiles. "Indeed," University of Maryland drug-policy expert Peter Reuter argues in an article in The Milken Institute Review, "leaf prices have varied enormously over the last decade, while the retail price of cocaine has steadily fallen."

Then, there's the sheer perversity of raising the price of something as a way to discourage its production. As Patrick L. Clawson and Rensselaer W. Lee write in their book The Andean Cocaine Industry, "It is not clear why Washington thinks that a crop reduction program raises the income of Midwestern wheat farmers but lowers the income of Andean coca farmers." Crop eradication also can't be much of an obstacle to the captains of the drug trade, because they have an enormous incentive to pay whatever it takes to keep coca in production, given the enormous retail bonanza awaiting them on U.S. streets ( which, of course, is itself a product of the drug war-otherwise, there's no reason heroin, say, would cost more than gold ).

This is the nub of the problem: The very illegality of drugs makes the drug business so lucrative that new actors will be drawn to it, no matter what. Imagine, by way of comparison, setting a $100 million lottery prize, then expecting people never to try to buy a ticket.

According to a recent RAND study on Colombia, "By one gauge, the 520 metric tons of cocaine that Colombia produced in 1999 could, at an average retail street price in the United States of one hundred dollars a gram ( or $100 million per metric ton ), have netted as much as $52 billion-more than the gross domestic product of many nations."

The other supply-side policy, besides eradication, is targeting traffickers. The idea here is both to collapse the price of coca leaf, since there will be less demand for it from the dead, jailed, or scared-off traffickers, and to raise the retail price, since there will be less of the product on the streets. Thus, coca farmers and addicts will be discouraged all at once. This theory has arguably been demonstrated a few times, for at least a few months after major disruptions in trafficking networks.

But the market always bounces back. And, as in the case of the price of coca leaf, the costs to traffickers of seized drugs, abandoned or shot-down airplanes, etc., is minuscule compared to the eventual retail payoff.

So, the cat never catches its tail. "Interdiction, in fact, seizes a quite high share-perhaps one-third-of the cocaine that is destined for the United States," argues Peter Reuter. "Nonetheless, this still leaves plenty of product to support the large United States cocaine market at prices that are modest by historical standards." All the splashy successes, all the record-setting busts, fade away in the relentless reality of an insatiable and highly profitable market. Take the high-profile smashing of the Medellin and Cali cartels in Colombia. "The weakening of the cartel structure in Colombia and the impressive U.S. seizures of more than 760 tons of cocaine between 1990 and 1996 have had no discernible effect on the underlying traffic infrastructure and on the availability of the drug domestically," report Clawson and Lee. "Indeed, the price per pure gram of cocaine in the United States reached a 15-year low in 1996, declining 37 percent since 1990."

Crushing the cartels, which may have been a worthy goal in its own right since they were massive and corrupting criminal organizations, has just-in typical drug-war fashion-created another, in some ways more difficult, problem in Colombia. The drug trade is now dominated by smaller, looser groups that have been more difficult to fight, and that include the various guerrilla forces-both the Marxist FARC and the paramilitary vigilantes-in Colombia's civil war. Hence, Plan Colombia. It will throw everything in the drug-war arsenal at the problem, disrupting trafficking networks, eradicating crops, and promoting alternative development. The essential dishonesty of the plan is that it pretends to be just a war on drugs when it is really meant to be a war on FARC ( the hideous paramilitaries, also involved in the drug trade, won't get the same attention ).

Plan Colombia has a two-step strategic thrust of starving the guerrillas of drug funds and, consequentially, forcing them to the bargaining table.

Both steps are flawed.

Although FARC reaps major benefits from the drug trade, it's not clear exactly how dependent it is on drug money.

Even if all drug funds were to dry up-which is extremely unlikely, given the progress of the drug war in the Andes to date-there would still be plenty of financing available through various protection rackets and kidnapping, Colombia's other explosive growth industry. ( By one estimate, according to the RAND study, Colombian guerrillas account for up to 30 percent of all kidnappings in the world. ) Indeed, another, smaller guerrilla group, ELN, has managed to prosper in Colombia without much connection to the drug trade.

The second step speaks of a deeper problem.

In Colombia, it's as though a particularly gruesome Aeschylus play were continually in production; it features the most vicious and extensive carnage this side of the Congo. FARC is soaked in this bloody culture, which is why it has been in the field for four decades.

For them, negotiations are just another stop on the way to more fighting.

FARC won't go away unless it is beaten, but the Colombia elite seem to have little taste for that. The military budget is still relatively small, and the country's most prominent families have all been victimized by kidnapping, and so are accustomed to trying to cut deals with thugs.

Vanquishing FARC might well require a dose of Fujimorism, but that would probably prompt a cutoff of U.S. aid. As it is, Washington is backing a policy that is likely to fail, will require an increased U.S. commitment, and eventually will force us to admit the fight in Colombia has little to do with whether American high-school kids will snort cocaine.

Indeed, the larger deception behind Plan Colombia is that the drug war, as currently conceived, is winnable. And because people readily believe this, U.S. entanglement in a nasty, decades-long civil war is an easy political sell. Bill Bennett, in a recent op-ed piece entitled "The Drug War Worked Once-It Can Again," wrote, "According to a national drug survey, between 1979 and 1992, the most intense period of antidrug efforts, the rate of illegal drug use dropped by more than half, while marijuana use decreased by two-thirds. Cocaine use dropped by three-fourths between 1985 and 1992." But in Bennett's telling, after all of Reagan and Bush's hard work, Bill Clinton threw the drug-war machinery into reverse: "Between 1992 in 1999, rates of current drug use-defined as using once a month or more-increased by 15 percent.

Rates of marijuana use increased 11 percent."

This interpretation-endorsed by John Walters as well-just doesn't add up. As Jacob Sullum points out, drug use peaked in 1979, two years before Reagan took office and three years before any of his policies could have had any effect. Drug-taking habits move with fashion and in epidemic boom-and-bust trends that policymakers may have some influence over, but not as much as Bill Bennett press releases suggest.

That the amount of cocaine consumed in the U.S. rose into the mid 1980s, then leveled off ( was Reagan "soft on cocaine" in his first term? ), may have as much to do with the 1986 death of basketball star Len Bias as with any public policy.

As for the increases Bennett attacks in the Clinton administration, they have been small in absolute terms, and mostly involve high-school kids smoking more marijuana, the least harmful illegal drug and one about which attitudes have been softening ( marijuana use by high-schoolers has also declined since 1997 ).

Indeed, the last two decades should have been fatal to the Walters theory that a supply-side crackdown reduces supply and increases price, thereby curtailing use. About half of high-school seniors reported that cocaine was readily available to them in 1999, roughly the same figure as in 1991, and the number for marijuana-80 percent or more-has remained steady since the mid 1970s. As for price, Peter Reuter reports in a new book written with Robert MacCoun ( Drug War Heresies ) that "during the period of increasingly tough enforcement, prices for cocaine and heroin have fallen steadily since 1981; by 1995, after adjusting for inflation, they were only about one-third of their 1981 levels. For marijuana, prices rose steadily and substantially from 1981 to 1992 and then fell in the next four years back close to their 1981 level."

And what Bennett and Walters don't ever dare acknowledge, since it is fatally inconvenient to their case, is the boom in arrests that has continued to roll right through the supposedly lax Clinton years.

Reuter and MacCoun again: "The total punishment levied for drug control purposes has increased massively since 1981, when concern with cocaine became prominent . . . The number of commitments to state and federal prison has risen over tenfold during the same time period. By 1996, there were over 400,000 people in prison or jail serving time for selling or using drugs; the comparable figure for 1980 was about 31,000." According to the authors, "arrests for simple [marijuana] possession have doubled in the last five years." If this is an insufficiently vigorous drug war, what would ever be an adequate one?

This is the deeper point.

Skepticism about the drug war is often associated with libertarianism. But it also reflects a conservative distrust of utopian schemes, with impossible goals ( eliminating certain forms of intoxication in the United States ) to be pursued by nearly limitless means.

Government can't straighten the crooked timber of humanity, the impulse for euphoria and/or oblivion constituting one form of that crookedness. By what silly presumption does John Walters think he can set the fashion at nightclubs and raves all over America? By what bizarre fantasy does he think he can do it with Black Hawks and pesticides? With enough resources, the United States may yet succeed in disrupting coca production and trafficking in Colombia-before they reassert themselves in some new, unexpected way.

Poor John Walters. He has many victories in front of him.

Source: National Review (US)
Published: June 20, 2001
Issue: Vol. LIII, No. 13, 09 Jul 2001
Copyright: 2001 National Review
Contact: letters@nationalreview.com
Website: http://www.nationalreview.com/

Colombia Drug War News
http://freedomtoexhale.com/colombia.htm

CannabisNews Justice Archives
http://cannabisnews.com/news/list/justice.shtml


Home    Comment    Email    Register    Recent Comments    Help

 
Comment #3 posted by Sudaca on June 22, 2001 at 10:02:00 PT
Where are the barons?
Where they can make decisions that make the following make sense:

"It is not clear why Washington thinks that a crop reduction program raises the income of Midwestern wheat farmers but lowers the income of Andean coca farmers."



[ Post Comment ]

 
Comment #2 posted by Ethan Russo, MD on June 22, 2001 at 05:31:28 PT:

Pithy Maxim
Eliminate the profit to eliminate the problem.

[ Post Comment ]
 
Comment #1 posted by kaptinemo on June 22, 2001 at 04:28:19 PT:

Truer words were rarely said
"The economics of drug production will always bedevil drug warriors.

How true. And glaringly obvious. But for some other reasons, entirely.

I invite the curious to obtain a Colombian perspective on this:

Drug War Hypocrisy:The Deadly Mathematics of the Cocaine Equation By Juan Salas, El Tiempo, Bogota
http://www.colombiasupport.net/warondrugs/index.html

Because Sr. Salas dares point out something that this article - and so many here in the States - generally have an unseemly haste to gloss over: the extant to which the heavy hand of corruption within the US law enforcement apparatus must perforce exist in order to maintain the entire trade. If it wasn't there, none of this would be possible.

From the article:
"The key to the horror of drug trafficking can be found in the following figures, as they were given out by the former Colombian Fiscal Gustavo de Greiff: a kilo of
processed cocaine fetches about $2,000 in Colombia whilst in the US it sells for $60,000."

"From $2,000 to $60,000 is an incredible profit margin, but between these two figures is hidden the biggest surprise: how is this windfall shared? Crossing the US
border, bribing customs, sea and airport, and other officials costs $3500 per kilo of cocaine -- cocaine recently arrived in the US costs some $5500 per kilo."

"A part of this $3500 transportation cost is obviously used to blind radar systems and to get information about U.S. spy plane movement and to pay customs people
on the US border to see, hear and say nothing.
So let's say we now have our $5500 kilo of cocaine in the US. This same kilo will fetch usually $20,000 in the U.S. Such a splendid profit margin we can suppose, in many cases, ends up in the pockets of Colombian, Mexican or other foreign drug traffickers."

"Up to this point the DEA has got things right: the big Colombian drug barons, and others, are doing big business producing and transporting white powder from the
impoverished South of the continent to the rich paradise in the North."

and here he gets to the meat:

"But the next stage in the deal is so surprising that it should lead the DEA and other anti-Colombian hawks to hold their tongues in check. This stage is where the
North Americans, having bought their $20,000 kilo of cocaine, set in train the business of selling it via a chain of intermediaries for the phenomenal sum of $60,000.

"A kilo of cocaine leaves $40,000 in the pockets of the North American dealers and only $20,000 go to those abominable Latin drug barons. What a surprise. These
figures, which are only statistical approximations and cannot be applied to each and every transaction reveal the horror of it all: the big share of drug trafficking is
North American and by extension, for sure, the big drug barons are North American."

There it is, in black and white. But he goes further:

"And where are they? You may ask yourself if there have been any stories of any big North American drug traffickers being arrested. Where are the Al Capones of the New York, Chicago and Bronx drug scenes? Where are today's incorruptibles? Silence. The U.S. prisons are seething with hundreds of thousands of blacks,latinos and other rejects, arrested for selling a few grams in bars and alleyways. But the gringo barons: where are they?"

For that answer, you'll have to look in the boardrooms of major banking houses, top-level government offices, multinational corporations...and your own local police precinct. Because, like the air, the corruption is everywhere.

I'll say it again: Treason doth never prosper; what's the reason? When treason doth prosper, none dare call it treason!




[ Post Comment ]


  Post Comment
Name:        Password:
E-Mail:

Subject:

Comment:   [Please refrain from using profanity in your message]

Link URL:
Link Title:


Return to Main Menu


So everyone may enjoy this service and to keep it running, here are some guidelines: NO spamming, NO commercial advertising, NO flamming, NO illegal activity, and NO sexually explicit materials. Lastly, we reserve the right to remove any message for any reason!

This web page and related elements are for informative purposes only and thus the use of any of this information is at your risk! We do not own nor are responsible for visitor comments. In accordance with Title 17 U.S.C. Section 107 and The Berne Convention on Literary and Artistic Works, Article 10, news clippings on this site are made available without profit for research and educational purposes. Any trademarks, trade names, service marks, or service names used on this site are the property of their respective owners. Page updated on June 21, 2001 at 14:24:03